Commercial Farmers' Union of Zimbabwe

Commercial Farmers' Union of Zimbabwe

***The views expressed in the articles published on this website DO NOT necessarily express the views of the Commercial Farmers' Union.***

Reforming land reform

Reforming land reform

http://www.theindependent.co.zw/

Thursday, 21 July 2011 19:13

MORE than two decades after the enactment of the Land Acquisition Act, and 
commencement of its implementation 10 years later, Zimbabwe’s land reform 
programme continues to be a major disaster.  Whilst it cannot be credibly 
argued that land reform was not very necessary and was grievously long 
overdue, nevertheless the way that Zimbabwe sought to achieve that 
critically needed reform was, and continues to be catastrophic, and a 
principal trigger of the economic morass that has afflicted Zimbabwe and its 
people.

It was incomprehensible and untenably unjust that for more than half a 
century, indigenous Zimbabweans were barred by the evil  Land Apportionment 
Act from possessing land.  They were unable to engage in the very foundation 
of the economy, being agriculture, save for farming on communal lands and as 
labour on non-indigenously owned farms.  The policies that prevailed under 
non-indigenous domination were oppressive and unjust in the extreme and 
needed to be radically and constructively reformed although tragically, that 
reform was not only disastrously belated, but also very substantially 
ineffective.

As a result, agriculture was subjected to an avalanche of decline.  As 
against being the source of food for all the country’s people, and an 
exporter of much produce to neighbouring states (to such extent that it was 
known as the region’s breadbasket), crops diminished such that Zimbabwe 
became intensively dependent upon international food aid, and upon imports 
which it could not readily fund.  More than 300 000 farm labourers became 
unemployed, and the average number of their dependants being six, almost two 
million were tragically impoverished.  Foreign exchange resources diminished 
to a large extent as the export tobacco crop decreased over an eight year 
period, from 237 million kgs in 2001 to less than 50 million kgs in 2008. 
Agriculture’s downstream economy was negatively impacted, through the loss 
of spending by farmers and their labour.  The entire economy contracted 
exponentially.

The need to address the land ownership inequalities was recognised at the 
pre-Independence Lancaster House negotiations in 1979, to the extent that 
Britain, the former colonial power, pledged to make significant funding 
available for indigenous land acquisition.  That acquisition was to be on a 
“willing buyer, willing seller” basis, and over the first five years of 
Independence Britain honoured that commitment, disbursing substantial 
amounts to fund the first phases of indigenous land ownership.  The next 
step towards land reform was that farms could not be sold, and ownership 
transferred, without the transacting parties first obtaining from government 
a “certificate of no interest”, which constituted governmental consent to 
the sales.  Progressively, there was increasing indigenous ownership, 
although not to a very major extent, as most of the populace could not fund 
land acquisitions.  Agriculture continued to thrive and to be the country’s 
economic mainstay.

But then government went berserk.  Driven substantially by endemic racial 
hatred, desires of self-enrichment, hatred of the former colonialists, and 
perceived entrenchment of voter support, it embarked upon the devastating 
pursuit of vesting ownership of all rural lands in the state, and 
acquisition of millions and millions of hectares of farm land, embarking on 
much ill-considered and indiscriminate redistribution.  And it did so 
without any payment of compensation, contending that any compensation for 
land had to be paid by Britain. Although government undertook to compensate 
for improvements and movables on the land, more than 10 years later, it has 
failed to do so.

If agriculture is to be restored to its former glory, and if Zimbabwe is to 
enjoy comprehensive economic recovery, it is of extreme urgency that the 
ill-conceived and grossly mismanaged land reform programme be revamped. 
That reformation does not mean a recission, but a restructuring, to be 
economically effective, just and morally correct.  Distressingly, the Medium 
Term Policy  for Zimbabwe’s economy does not address the essentially needed 
reforms.

Key elements of the required reforms to regain total agricultural viability 
are:
Ideally, absolute ownership of the lands must vest in the farmers, and not 
in the state, and therefore title deeds must be reintroduced.  Without 
ownership, the farmers have no collateral with which to secure the funding 
needed as working capital, and for development and acquisition of essential 
equipment.  Without access to adequate funds, the farmer has no prospects of 
achieving viable operations.  If (given its ill-conceived, fixative 
attitude), the reinstatement of title deeds is reprehensibly abhorrent to 
government, then the compromise, although not ideal, would be for the 
current 99 year leases to be readily transferrable.  Currently, leases have 
no collateral value for not only are they incapable of cession, but in 
addition, the 99 year tenure is hypothetical, for the state has the power to 
terminate the leases on three months’ notice.

Land ownership or lease should not be racially-based but be available to any 
and all  Zimbabweans, irrespective of race, and be conditional only upon the 
meritorious and productive usage of the land.  Linked to this reform, 
formerly productive non-indigenous farmers should be accorded opportunities 
of resuming farming operations, thereby not only enhancing the extent of 
agricultural production, but also according new farmers access to the 
long-developed skills and experience of those farmers.

Full compensation needs to be given to those who lost their farms.  That 
compensation must be for the land and all that was thereon when the farms 
were expropriated by the state.  Government should not, and cannot, abdicate 
its responsibility for that compensation, deviously and without foundation 
seeking to attribute liability to the United Kingdom.  Britain honoured its 
Lancaster House obligations, and it was the Zimbabwean government that 
disentitled the legitimate landowners (many of whom had had governmental 
acquisition consent by way of the certificates of no interest).  Of especial 
urgency is where there is compensatory obligation in terms of the numerous 
Bilateral Investment Promotion and Protection Agreements, which Zimbabwe has 
consistently flouted.  That default is one of the greatest deterrents to 
Foreign Direct Investment, which investment is a major key need for 
Zimbabwean economic recovery.

Agricultural policies must be conducive to the viability of the sector. 
Parastatals such as the Grain Marketing Board and Cold Storage Company must 
timeously pay fair, market-related prices for produce, and agriculturally 
counterproductive policies should not be pursued.

If government could at least recognise the error of its ways, have the 
maturity to reverse them, and put national interests ahead of its own, in 
time agriculture will again thrive, and be the mainstay of the 
economy. -Eric Bloch

Facebook
Twitter
LinkedIn
WhatsApp

Fresh Chingwizi headache for govt

Fresh Chingwizi headache for govt    12/7/2019 Source: Fresh Chingwizi headache for govt | Newsday (News) BY TATENDA CHITAGU Survivors of the Tugwi-Mukosi floods in 2014

Read More »

ED dangles carrot to war veterans

ED dangles carrot to war veterans – NewsDay Zimbabwe   2/7/2019 By Everson Mushava PRESIDENT Emmerson Mnangagwa’s government has ordered all the country’s eight provincial

Read More »

New Posts: