Commercial Farmers' Union of Zimbabwe

Commercial Farmers' Union of Zimbabwe

***The views expressed in the articles published on this website DO NOT necessarily express the views of the Commercial Farmers' Union.***

Don’t be fooled: Zimbabwe’s land reform is no success

Don’t be fooled: Zimbabwe’s land reform is no success

http://www.groundup.org.za/content/don%E2%80%99t-be-fooled-zimbabwe%E2%80%99s-land-reform-no-success

July 31, 2013 –
Jack Lewis

OPINION
It is election day in Zimbabwe. This is a good day to reconsider the 
Zimbabwean land reform experience and what to make of it, especially as we 
consider what should be done about land reform in South Africa.
When you think of Zimbabwean land reform, you think about the “fast track” 
reform from 2000 that saw the majority of commercial farms either broken up 
and handed in smaller allotments to about 125,000 small farmers and 50,000 
larger small-holders, or grabbed by members of the Zimbabwean elite. How did 
this come about?

A little report in Tuesday’s Times is revealing. Erina Murwira, now in her 
80s and living on the outskirts of Harare will be voting for the MDC. Why? 
“I stopped supporting Mugabe a long time ago … he has not taken care of us 
old people. He has failed us,” she said. She has not forgiven Mugabe for 
stopping her pension in the 1990s. To understand why Erina’s pension was 
stopped we need to understand why the fast track land reform became a 
political necessity for the ruling Zanu-PF dictatorship. It had little to do 
with justice and a new economic path, as some naive researchers have 
suggested, and everything to do with bloated plutocrats hanging on to the 
state at any cost.

Following independence in 1980, the new government in Zimbabwe resettled 
52,000 families on 2.5 million hectares purchased from European commercial 
farmers. Plans called for the acquisition and resettlement of an additional 
five million hectares. Initially it was a great success. The UN’s Food and 
Agricultural Organisation reported that smallholder maize production doubled 
from 738,000 tonnes in 1980 to 1.3 million tonnes in 1986 and that 
underlying this was “the inheritance of a productive public agricultural 
research system, a quadrupling in the number of government-provided loans to 
smallholders, a sharp increase in guaranteed producer prices and a 30-fold 
increase in the number of Government Marketing Board (GMB) grain-buying 
depots and collection points.” The government also spent money on education 
and health.

Why did the government falter? A large part of the reason, and one that is 
given far too little importance by contemporary writers on Zimbabwean land 
reform, was the coup which Mugabe initiated in 1982 in Matebaleland against 
the Ndebele stronghold of Zapu, the main opposition party led by Joshua 
Nkomo. Over 20,000 people were butchered in the “Gukurahundi” and Mugabe’s 
regime became a de-facto dictatorship. It shocks me that most writers on 
Zimbabwe’s 2000 land reform, Mahmood Mandani being a notable exception, are 
largely silent on the anti-democratic nature of the Mugabe regime which has 
looted the Zimbabwean state for private gain.

By 1990, the government was broke with debt service obligations consuming 
33% of its budget. Zimbabwe was obliged to seek help from the International 
Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank which demanded structural adjustment. 
Erina Murwira’s old age pension was a casualty of these IMF imposed cuts. 
Markets were deregulated and public expenditure reduced. At the same time 
drought and poor agricultural yields further restricted government revenue.

Between 1991 and 1996 manufacturing shrank by 14% and GDP per capita 
declined by 5.8%. Government spending on education declined by over 30% as 
wages for teachers were slashed and health spending declined. In desperation 
it printed more money to keep social spending going, starting a vicious 
inflationary spiral, already 50% by 1999.

A parasitic ruling clique had by 1999 seized all organs of state. It was 
hugely unpopular and effectively lost the 2000 elections to the newly formed 
MDC: it was only the appointment of 30 seats from amongst the chiefs that 
gave Mugabe control of Parliament. It was this shock that precipitated the 
fast track land reform to shore up the rural vote which was in near revolt 
against Mugabe’s misrule.

The result of the land reform was massive economic dislocation. However, 
recently a group of researchers led by Ian Scoones in the UK has stimulated 
discussion on Zimbabwe land reform. Scoones found that many recipients of 
small holdings have in fact increased production and are better off as a 
result of receiving land.

It would indeed have been surprising if the perhaps 160,000 smallholder 
beneficiaries from among the very poor and 51,000 beneficiaries from among 
small and medium-scale black farmers had not increased production. But this 
increase in smallholder production, which is still wholly inadequate to feed 
Zimbabwe, has come at the cost disrupting the link between Zimbabwean 
agriculture and industry. It has further undermined state revenue and made 
impossible any of the support to smallholders that had been responsible for 
the large increases in production in the 1980-85 period.

Over a decade since the land redistribution, up to 70,000 
households—perhaps 350 000 people–remain displaced, living in poverty on 
the urban peripheries of Zimbabwe’s cities and towns. But the total 
displacement was far greater. Many more, perhaps two to three million, did 
not receive land and lost their livelihoods in the cities and were forced 
into economic migrancy, mainly in South Africa and Botswana. Many others 
were forced into labour tenancy, non-wage and casual work on the 
redistributed land. This loss of population has reduced domestic demand and 
contributed to loss of revenue for the state.

Loss of agricultural output from large scale farms not made up by small 
holders

Prior to land reform, Zimbabwe produced not only sufficient maize, wheat, 
and other grains, but a surplus was exported. Since land reform there has 
been a critical dependence on imports. Approximately 1.8 million tonnes of 
maize are required annually to meet the country’s needs against the current 
national yield of a little more than 300 thousand tonnes per year. Since 
2000, there have been 13 consecutive years of food deficits and the United 
Nations has recently appealed for more than $100 million dollars to feed 1.7 
million Zimbabweans in 2013. Production of wheat continues to be constrained 
by lack of access to inputs and an unstable power supply, arising from a 
bankrupt state that cannot maintain and invest in infrastructure.

It is a standard refrain from those arguing for the great gains made by 
smallholder agriculture that these figures are not to be trusted. But 
Zimbabwe’s Minister of Finance, Tendai Biti, wrote this year that “We have 
received the second crop assessment report, which records the unacceptable 
situation of a major decline in agricultural output… Our strategic grain 
reserve is less than 40,000 metric tonnes. We are in the process of 
importing 150,000 metric tonnes of maize from Zambia.”

One of the main contributing factors to agriculture’s massive decline is 
that the majority of the new farmers did not have the capital necessary to 
fund operations and could not access funding because of the chaotic manner 
in which the expropriations were carried out. The state claims title to all 
farmlands, only making land available to new farmers by way of leases. The 
state therefore denied those farmers the collateral security necessary to 
access working capital for farming operations.

Shrinking economy and job losses equals less state revenue and greater 
fiscal debt

750,000 jobs were lost between the peak employment in 1998 and 2011. Only 
14% of the workforce has a paid, permanent job in the formal economy. Using 
the most generous definition of informal employment, at least half the 
workforce does not have a job. The collapse of the commercial farming sector 
has contributed significantly to a steep decline in state revenues, the 
collapse of state services and hyperinflation as the government desperately 
printed money to keep going, and eventually the abandonment of the 
Zimbabwean dollar in 2008 in favour of the US dollar and the rand.

A recent study by the Development Bank of Southern Africa found that the 
Zimbabwean government “currently employs an estimated 250,000 people 
generating a wage bill of more than US$960 million, working out at more than 
70% of revenue collections, 60% of the total budget, and more than 15% of 
GDP.”

Zimbabwe Government Debt to GDP averaged 80% from 1990 until 2011, reaching 
an all time high of 151% in December of 2011. The relevance of this for land 
reform is that there can be no question of government support for 
infrastructure, veterinary and agricultural support services, grain silos, 
transport and so on–things that Scoones and others would agree are 
essential–because the state is bankrupt.

An economy driven into the informal sector and reliant on smallholding 
agriculture cannot provide the revenue to sustain a modern state. The mining 
sector, driven by foreign multinationals despite the enrichment disguise of 
“indigenisation” does not on its own do anything to promote local industry.

Of course the blame for all this does not lay solely with ZANU-PF and its 
ruling clique. If there had been greater international support for land 
reform, more willingness from large scale farmers to redistribute and 
support both small scale and larger black farmers as well as less pressure 
from the IMF, World Bank and the World Trade Organisation to liberalise and 
reign in expenditure on agricultural support, things might not have ended up 
as they have.

Be that as it may, it doesn’t change the reality that there is no 
independent small scale route to greater well-being once large scale 
commercial agriculture has been undermined. From an analytical point of view 
it seems Scoones and others seems happy to ignore all of this when 
discussing the impact of land reform, taking increased production and 
incomes for smallholders as if this is the only socially relevant criteria. 
It seems to me to be historically blind to argue that there is a Korean path 
for Zimbabwe. Korean land reform occurred with the United States fully 
committed to its success in an era of sustained global economic expansion 
and driven by cold war era concerns. None of these conditions pertain to 
Zimbabwe.

The meaning of all this for South Africa should be clear, especially when 
taken against the smaller proportion of the population dependent on the land 
for a living. Land reform requires the state to have the capacity to provide 
post settlement support, secure title and cheap capital. Zimbabwe shows that 
undermining the large farms undermines the capacity of the state to provide 
these things. Zimbabwe’s smallholders deserve a state that provides such 
support. And it cannot be a Zanu-PF-Mugabe state.

Facebook
Twitter
LinkedIn
WhatsApp

Fresh Chingwizi headache for govt

Fresh Chingwizi headache for govt    12/7/2019 Source: Fresh Chingwizi headache for govt | Newsday (News) BY TATENDA CHITAGU Survivors of the Tugwi-Mukosi floods in 2014

Read More »

ED dangles carrot to war veterans

ED dangles carrot to war veterans – NewsDay Zimbabwe   2/7/2019 By Everson Mushava PRESIDENT Emmerson Mnangagwa’s government has ordered all the country’s eight provincial

Read More »

New Posts:

From the archives

Posts from our archive you may find interesting