Commercial Farmers' Union of Zimbabwe

Commercial Farmers' Union of Zimbabwe

***The views expressed in the articles published on this website DO NOT necessarily express the views of the Commercial Farmers' Union.***

Making a land bank work for Zim

Making a land bank work for Zim

Source: Making a land bank work for Zim – The Zimbabwe Independent

LAST week cabinet approved a proposal to repurpose Agribank Private Limited (Agribank) into a land bank.In last week’s instalment, we cited the pitfalls associated with a land bank, citing our domestic and international history of land banks. We noted that land banks are largely creatures of national politics and tend to make sub-optimal business models that regularly need the taxpayer to cover the financial holes they create.

Today’s instalment explores ways in which a land bank in Zimbabwe can be made to work. This article is not looking at how the land bank should be funded. It looks at the more critical issue: how can the proposed land bank ensure it books quality assets (high quality borrowers)?

It would be naive to expect government to let the private sector have a controlling stake in a land bank given the political sensitivity of agriculture in Zimbabwe. Political influence will have to be taken as an environmental factor that must shape an appropriate strategic response.

Statistically, 90% of farmers in Zimbabwe are from old resettlement areas, communal areas and A1 farms. These do not have land rights that are acceptable as collateral by commercial banks. About 95% of the national herd is in the hands of these same farmers.

Apparently, these same farmers account for 70-80% of Zimbabwe’s grain production. Historically, non-titled black farmers produced most of our grain in the post-Independence era before and after the fast-track land reform programme.

This dominant cohort is the one that gave the Agriculture Finance Corporation (AFC), Agribank’s immediate predecessor financial challenges as the AFC made loans of small amounts to about 100 000 farmers. These farmers were given token loans by the AFC for inputs based on a track record of output. To get around this challenge of issuing loans supported by disproportinately high economic costs, the land bank should treat the non-A2 farmers as business people, not as some charity cases that should be pitied upon. It is not true that these farmers have no securitisable assets; they do.

They have biological assets in the form of livestock such as goats, sheep and cattle. We need to look no further than the ancient Near East culture — the wealthiest people were so-called based on the biological assets they held. In the Bible, notable figures classed as fabulously wealthy such as Abraham, Isaac, Jacob, Job and Nabal had their wealth anchored on biological assets.

We know that 90% of Zimbabwe’s national herd is in the hands of these non-A2 farmers — that is serious wealth. That wealth is private property and therefore is transferrable and tradable. The land bank has no option but to consider goats, sheep and cattle as securitisable assets against which they can lend money to farmers.

All that is needed is a mental shift. If we do not, history will record that whereas the Union Jack came down in 1980, it remained flying at full mast in our minds. The land bank can form a subsidiary in agro-business that holds these assets. These biological assets grow by way of multiples — essentially they are top quality assets that behave like loans themselves — but infinitely better. The livestock deposited as security can potentially give birth (this is like interest). If the land bank treats non-A2 farmers as respectable business people, the bank will unlock a very profitable clientele that needs no subsidies and hand outs from government.

On the basis of biological assets, the land bank can issue medium-term loans for critical farming infrastructure such as boreholes, weirs and off-grid power solutions. A dedicated water and off-grid power infrastructure fund is needed to allow non-A2 farmers build powerful water and power infrastructure. This will allow non-A1 farmers to climate-proof their production and increase their productivity.

The second hurdle to be overcome by the land bank is dealing with A2 farmers. These have the largest farms but have no transferrable or tradable land rights. To a large extent, it can be argued that A2 farmers are the direct replacement of former white commercial farmers.

The AFC, from its inception on April 1, 1971, dealt with a business cohort of tested commercial farmers with a proven track record of production. This cohort presented lending business opportunities for the AFC within acceptable risk levels. Even post-Independence, the titled commercial farmers were the most profitable cohort for the AFC. Post-2000, A2 farmers presented a business risk beyond the commercial lending risk appetites and benchmarks for two reasons. First, land reform made land as securitisable asset redundant.

It must be noted that the post-Independence AFC competed with commercial banks for the commercial farmers due to the high quality credit ratings of the commercial farmers. The high quality commercial farmers were a result of market selection from the 1920s — the white farmers who failed at farming were exited from the agro-business and those that survived did so because of business ability, skill and accumulated experience.

Post-2000, A2 farmers were selected by a political mechanism and are still being retained by a non-market mechanism. Commercially speaking, bad A2 farmers have not been de-selected. Other A2 farmers have farm sizes that do not match their skill levels. This is the cohort that will give the land bank the biggest business headache. It is a reversal of trends; commercial farmers were the best clientele for the AFC while non-A2 farmers were the more problematic business segment.

What is the best way around this sad reality? There are two realistic options that can be combined. The third option is not viable under our current political circumstances. First, the land bank should treat A2 farmers the way the AFC did to the non-commercial farmers. The land bank has to lend A2 farmers based on a track record of output.

Admittedly, this will limit the loan amounts they will be issued. These A2 farmers have already benefitted from non-market government farming schemes and they are expected to have some of the equipment they got. These benefits should reflect in their production records.

The second option is for the land bank to accept biological assets owned by A2 farmers as securitisable assets. The risk of default should fall on A2 farmers, not the taxpayer. The third option is making the 99-year leases marketable. That would allow the market to exit unsuccessful A2 farmers and select productive farmers. This third option is not within the control of the land bank; the land bank cannot strategise on promises of making A2 farm leases transferrable — it will be strategic naivety.

In short, the land bank should lend to both non-A2 and A2 farmers based on biological assets and a track record of production. Farming is a business. Business people are not charity cases. As such, the land bank cannot be a charitable organisation.

Chulu is a management consultant and a classic grounded theory researcher who has published research in an academic peer-reviewed international journal. — [email protected].

Facebook
Twitter
LinkedIn
WhatsApp

$2,5bn allocation for ex-farmers

$2,5bn allocation for ex-farmers   The Herald 26/11/2021 Martin Kadzere-Business Reporter Zimbabwe remains firmly committed to implementing the Global Compensation Agreement (GPA) with white former

Read More »

New Posts: